Home | WebMail |

      Calgary | Regions | Local Traffic Report | Advertise on Action News | Contact

BusinessAnalysis

Oil-led deflation can be good, bad or ugly

Even as oil claws its way back from recent lows, the falling price of crude has highlighted the dangerous effects of deflation. But as central banks consider what to do, they must distinguish between good, bad and ugly deflation, Don Pittis writes.

Not all deflation is the same. In this case, cheaper oil wears the white hat for now

Central bankers worry about the threat of deflation, as consumers and investors could hold off on spending, leading to a vicious spiral of falling prices. (Larry Downing/Reuters)

When you fill up your car with cheap gas, there's a group of economists who just hate it.That's because in many parts of the world the biggest worry foreconomic stability is theplague of falling prices.

It's called deflation. Many economists consider it to be a dangerousdisease that has spread from Japan to the heart of Europe where this week even mighty Germany has succumbed. Now central bankersare worriedit could sweep the world.

Although oil prices have crossed back above $50 US, last year'scrash from over $100 is just now feeding into inflation calculations.Yesterday, central bankers in Australia and India joined the long listtrying to boost their economies and stave off deflation.

Inflation makes money worth less. Deflation has the opposite effect.

During times of, say, 10 per centinflation, if you carry a $100 bill around in your wallet for a year, at the end of the year it will buy 10 per cent less. But during 10 per centdeflation, keeping the same $100 will buy you10 per centmore. That sounds good.

But the reason deflation frightens economists is that falling pricesgohand in hand with economic stagnation. As with many economic phenomena, it is not absolutely clear whether deflation is the cause of recession, or whether it's the other way round.

As an economy weakens, businesses and consumersspend less and buy less. If the economy continues to crank out goods and services at just the same rate, the only way sellerscan entice customers tobuy the same amountis for sellers to cut prices.

Those who blamedeflation for recession say that when prices beginfalling, people and businesses tend to spend less. Why replacethatstove now when it will be cheaper in the spring? Why borrow to invest when what you will have to repaywill be worth more than when you borrowed it?

Good, bad or ugly

This week I ran across a great report on deflation from the U.S. National Bureau of Economic Research. The study, on the historic impact of deflation, was written in 2004, and has the advantage of not being biased by the current sense of crisis.

The NBERpaper says that deflation can be good, bad or ugly. And when it comes to deflation caused by the falling price of oil, that is the best kind of all.

"Gooddeflationsare those that arise from positive supply shocks," says the paper's authors.

In other words, as many people (including me) have said before, having lots of cheap oil, instead of an expensive shortage,is good for an economy. It is an effect similar to having a sudden supply of food aftera wartimefamine. There will be a shock to themarket as prices fall, but the result is clearly positive.

Historically, bad inflation is caused by recessions ofthe kind mentioned above where demand for goods and services falls in the face of constant supply.

The scary part is when things get ugly. And it is the ugly that central bankers are now desperately trying to avoid by once again flooding the world with money.

Severe recession

"Ugly deflations represent periods of steeply declining prices associated with severe recession," says the NBER report. "During these periods, declining prices arising from aggregate demand are sufficient to feedback to aggregate supply via onerous debt burdens, personal and corporate bankruptcies, financial crises and other adverse conditions."

To translate, the truly ugly happens when a perfect storm of deflation creates chaos and destruction, effectively breaking the structure of the economy.

People who hold cash get richer, but very few people own real cash. Most of their money is in some kind of debt or equity. But even as interest rates plunge, money held as debt also becomes worth more so borrowers crack under itsweight.

Loans are not paid back.Investors stop investing. Spenders stop spending. Companies go broke.Tax revenues fall asthe return on investment approaches zero.

Fortunately such ugly deflationary spirals are rare historical occurrences. But then again, that is whythey are best avoided.

The difficulty is that the solution to ugly deflation is not easy or obvious, especially when interest rates are already at historic lows.

Creating huge amounts of money, as Japan has been doing for years, does not necessarily break the cycle. Redistributing wealth by altering tax rates was tried in the 1930s.By some analysis, it was only the Second World Warthat snapped us out of the last ugly deflation.

In a way, the falling price of oil came at the worst possible moment. At a time of high inflation, it would have been just what the doctor ordered.

But if consumers and businesses misinterpret what should have been the good deflation of falling oil prices for thebaddeflation of recession, things could get ugly.